History of Ecological Economics
The Roots of Ecological Economics
Ecological economics (EE) is rooted in the diverse disciplines, life and times of a number of quite varied social and natural scientists and philosophers. The evolution of EE begins in the 18th century with the physiocrats' focus on the land as the source of wealth, and the discovery of the laws of thermodynamics in the 19th century that helped to reconcile biology and physics. It got a large boost with the economic and oil crises of the 20th century, and continues to focus on transitioning to less carbon intensive socio-economic systems (Cleveland, 1987, 1999; Czech, 2013; Rees, 2016).
The Political Economic Roots of EE: Physiocrats 1700’s
Beginning with the transition from mercantilism to classical economics, a French school of economics called physiocracy or ‘rule by nature’ briefly flourished. Quesnay (1758), Mirabeau (1763), and Dupont de Nemours (1767) developed the Tableau Economique (later adopted in neoclassical economics for general equilibrium and multisectoral input-output systems (Leontief, 1941; Meek, 1963)), and the conceptualization that the wealth of nations came directly from the surplus of the land. They theorized that the economy was driven by a Natural Law, composed of physical and moral laws, that transcended human free will (Quesnay, 1765). Adam Smith (1776) himself stated that “…with all its imperfections, [the Physiocratic system] is perhaps the nearest approximation to the truth that has yet been published upon the subject of political economy, and is upon that account well worth the consideration of every [human] who wishes to examine with attention the principles of that very important science.”
Thermodynamics 1800’s
The physiocrats' natural philosophy could not be developed further until the laws of thermodynamics and the meaning of energy, more generally, were discovered in the 19th century. Scientific curiosity led 28-year-old Sadi Carnot (1824) to stumble upon thermodynamics when he encountered an efficiency limit that steam engines could not exceed. His work on heat and energy transformations was an imperative for the bourgeoning industrial economy, and laid the foundation for Rudolf Clausius (1851, 1867) who, with the help of Lord Kelvin, formulated the first law of thermodynamics (which states that the total quantity of energy is conserved), and to develop the concept of entropy which allowed him to formalize the second law of thermodynamics (which states that the total quality of energy is not conserved).
The discovery of the laws of thermodynamics provided the scientific foundation to reconcile biology and physics, and provided natural and social scientists with the framework to observe and study the role of available energy flows in the coevolution of socio-economic systems. The following are three interesting applications of this framework at the turn of the 19th century. Herbert Spencer (1880) was an evolutionary biologist who realized that humans had evolved to deal with the tendency for increasing entropy by investing energy derived from nature to maintain their socio-economic systems. Sergei Podolinsky (1883) was a Ukrainian socialist who, after analyzing the thermodynamics of the economy and the labor theory of value, concluded that the scientific socialism of Frederick Engels was problematic because it relied on unlimited material expansion (which is the same sustainability problem of capitalism), and used concepts of energy flow and surplus that would later become the backbone of biophysical and ecological economics (Martinez-Alier and Naredo, 1982). Lastly, Wilhelm Ostwald (1907, 1911) was a German chemist, who believed that thermodynamics should be the foundation to all sciences, and applied his understanding of energy to explain that human history was marked by energy transformations.
Biophysical Economics 1900’s
Building on this thermodynamic foundation, the 20th century saw an insurrection of biophysical thought led by creative thinkers in the natural and social sciences who had the audacity to get out of their disciplinary boxes to question conventional thinking. The mathematical biologist Alfred Lotka (1922) described evolution as a race between energy transformers whose existence relied on capturing available energy in the most efficient way possible for the preservation of the species. In Elements of Physical Biology, Lotka (1925), introduces the term ‘biophysics’ (later adopted in biophysical economics), and the theories he lays out there (including “maximum power”) would become instrumental in the development of ecosystem science and energetics that system ecologists would apply decades later to natural and social systems.
Another prominent foundation of biophysical thinking is the work of Leslie A. White, an unconventional anthropologist who believed that the evolution of human culture was inextricably linked to energy. Writing during WWII, White (1943) described civilization as a form or organization of energy, and believed that culture, being a kind of behavior, could be treated as a manifestation of energy use. This led White to propose the law of cultural evolution (White's law) stating that “culture develops when the amount of energy harnessed by man per capita per year is increased; or as the efficiency of the technologicalmeans of putting this energy to work is increased; or, as both factors are simultaneously increased” (1943, p. 338). White (1949, 1959) believed that culture was composed of three subsystems (technological, sociological and ideological), and of these the technological system played the primary role as it allowed humans to harness energy and adapt to different environments.
Cottrell (1955, 1972), a railroad man turned sociologist, was also interested in the relationship between energy and human systems. Cottrell's (1955) approach in Energy and Society was both descriptive and comprehensive in explaining the processes that humans embarked on to exploit the energy available in nature. Cottrell theorized that energy quality and energy surplus were important factors as both influenced how much work could be done by socio-economic systems through subsidizing the productivity of labor and the discovery and development of more energy. Cottrell (1955) concluded that societies preferred energy resources and technologies that would generate the most energy surplus, and that the economic development depended on the continuous flow of energy surplus.
These biophysical critiques of economic growth came to a head during the birth of the U.S. environmental movement of the 1960s and early 1970s amidst growing concerns about the inability of neoclassical economics to take seriously its biophysical embeddedness (Boulding, 1966; Daly, 1968; Ayres and Kneese, 1969). Other important publications of that time included high profile publications on population growth (Ehrlich, 1968; Ehrlich and Holdren, 1971) and limits to growth (Meadows et al., 1972). The oil and economic crises of the 1970s and the rise of nuclear energy led a new wave of natural and social scientists to advance theories about the biophysical foundation of the economy that they thought were necessary to address environmental problems (e.g. Odum, 1971; Pimentel et al., 1973; Cook, 1976; Ayres, 1978). These years proved foundational to the development of ecological economics as a transdisciplinary alternative to the economic sub-disciplines of natural resource and environmental economics (Erickson, 1999), and were an exciting supplement to the graduate training (under Howard Odum) of the second author.
From Bioeconomics to Biophysical Economics to Ecological Economics
Would you like to read more and find all the references cited?